647 lines
36 KiB
Plaintext
647 lines
36 KiB
Plaintext
Libertarian Labor Review #13
|
||
Winter 1992-93, pages 33-39
|
||
|
||
MARKET ANARCHISM? CAVEAT EMPTOR!
|
||
Review by Jeff Stein
|
||
|
||
A Structured Anarchism : An Overview of Libertarian Theory and
|
||
Practice by John Griffin. Freedom Press (84b Whitechapel High
|
||
Street, London E1 7QX, U.K.), 1991. 38 pp., One pound.
|
||
|
||
In A Structured Anarchism, John Griffin argues that an
|
||
anarchist communist society, while a desirable goal in the
|
||
distant future, is not practical in the short-term. This is
|
||
because 1) people accustomed to a capitalist society aren't
|
||
culturally prepared for it, and 2) the modern economy is too
|
||
complicated to organize without the "self-regulation" of a market
|
||
system. Therefore Griffin calls for a series of short term
|
||
compromises to be made with classical liberal economics, and dubs
|
||
this "collectivist anarchism".
|
||
Griffin, unfortunately, doesn't understand collectivism nor
|
||
economics in general. He manages to garble and lump together the
|
||
views of Proudhon, Bakunin, and Malatesta. Bakunin was the only
|
||
collectivist of the three. Proudhon was a mutualist and
|
||
Malatesta, an anarchist communist. Besides mistakenly lumping
|
||
them all as "collectivists," Griffin makes an even bigger error
|
||
by equating collectivism with "market anarchism." Collectivism,
|
||
however, was not based on a market economy, but on a federally
|
||
coordinated system of "honest exchange" of products at their
|
||
labor cost. In a market system the prices of products are
|
||
determined according to their relative scarcity (ie. the "law of
|
||
supply and demand"). These are not the same thing.
|
||
Time and again, whether on the issue of markets or money,
|
||
Griffin proves he is in no position to lecture other anarchists
|
||
about their shaky grasp of economics. For instance, on page 22 he
|
||
writes, "The extraction of large amounts of unearned income by
|
||
the capitalists is a source of inflation, since too much money is
|
||
generated to buy the available goods, thus encouraging price
|
||
rises. Any inflation in a collectivist [sic] economy will not be
|
||
aggravated by this spurious money growth, since those who operate
|
||
it are remunerated only for work done."
|
||
The extraction of value by the capitalist out of the
|
||
workers' gross product has nothing whatsoever to do with the
|
||
money supply, since the capitalist does not print his/her own
|
||
money. (In effect, Griffin is saying that a robber creates money
|
||
when he steals your purse.) If what Griffin was saying were true,
|
||
the history of capitalism would be one long inflationary spiral,
|
||
without periodic economic depressions. On the contrary,
|
||
capitalism, if not interfered with by the state, tends towards
|
||
economic depressions (which cause deflation), since its constant
|
||
drive to reduce workers to low wages and unemployment has a
|
||
depressive effect.
|
||
In reality, the individual capitalist has very little
|
||
control over the money supply, which is a source of constant
|
||
consternation to the pro-laissez faire monetarists, like Hayek
|
||
and Milton Friedman, so oddly respected by Griffin (p.23). The
|
||
monetarists, however, do not suggest that the money supply be set
|
||
according to what has been produced, since according to them only
|
||
the market can determine the "true" value of these products
|
||
anyway. What the monetarists argue is that the state should
|
||
increase the money supply at a constant rate, so the capitalists
|
||
can plan ahead without having to worry about whether the state
|
||
economic planners will overreact to some minor market
|
||
"adjustment." According to classical laissez faire theory,
|
||
business cycles are inevitable and the market eventually corrects
|
||
itself. As for the effects these cycles have on working people
|
||
and the poor in the meantime, Hayek and Friedman could bloody
|
||
well care less. We should not forget the role of the "Chicago
|
||
Boys" (a group of Friedman's disciples) in running the economy of
|
||
the ruthless Pinochet regime in Chile. Griffin should freely
|
||
choose his mentors more carefully.
|
||
The state has always played a key role in the capitalist
|
||
market and monetary systems. First its role was as a defender of
|
||
private property, strike breaker of last resort, and as a
|
||
foundation of a (somewhat) stable currency. More recently it has
|
||
acted as a "pump primer," business subsidizer, and money lender
|
||
of the last resort. The so-called "Keynesian revolution" in
|
||
capitalist economics was not the beginning of the state's role in
|
||
the economy, just an attempt to better play that role in hopes of
|
||
making a more smooth running system and to stave off its
|
||
collapse. Griffin himself admits that "the manipulation of the
|
||
market by both the State and the Capitalists make the so-called
|
||
'free market' unfree." (p.24)
|
||
Yet by making this admission, Griffin has inadvertently
|
||
undermined one of his own arguments. On the one hand he attacks
|
||
the anarchist communist position because "it lacks empirical
|
||
justification from modern technological societies: it is not
|
||
enough in my view to dwell on its great ethical strength, and
|
||
gloss over organizational problems." (p.24) But on the other, he
|
||
doesn't hold his own doctrine up to the same standard. It may be
|
||
true that the market system "works" (perhaps in the since that
|
||
the inhabitants of Europe and North America haven't all starved
|
||
to death so far), but as he admits it is not a "free market," and
|
||
thus cannot be used to accurately predict what might happen in an
|
||
anarchist version. What of the many problems which would result
|
||
when the state no longer plays even its "limited" role in the
|
||
laissez faire sense? Who, for instance, would issue money in his
|
||
anarcho-market economy and guarantee its value? Although Griffin
|
||
cites Malatesta to back-up his claim for the necessity of money
|
||
during the transition towards an anarchist economy, he apparently
|
||
missed the Malatesta's admonition that "one should seek a way to
|
||
ensure that money truly represents the useful work by its
|
||
possessors..." (Malatesta: Life and Ideas, edited by Richards, p.
|
||
101). Griffin, in spite of his enthusiasm for money, doesn't
|
||
address this problem.
|
||
Unlike the anarchist communists, what Griffin lacks in
|
||
empirical evidence and practical concern for organizational
|
||
problems, he can not make up for with "ethical strength." For in
|
||
his conciliatory approach towards market economics, he is
|
||
prepared to sacrifice even the most basic anarchist principles,
|
||
including the abolition of wage slavery and an end to the private
|
||
ownership of the means of production: "I think we have to face up
|
||
to the fact that if some people want to be employed and others
|
||
want to employ them, then wage labor will continue. Recourse to
|
||
coercion by anarchists not involved should in my view be regarded
|
||
as a 'cure' which is worse than the disease. As long as
|
||
libertarian cultures constitute the dominant socializing force, I
|
||
do not think that the presence of small scale capitalist
|
||
enterprises is very important." (p.30)
|
||
Perhaps Griffin does not understand the implications of what
|
||
he has written. We are not talking about economic individualism,
|
||
self-employment or family businesses (which as long as they don't
|
||
employ non-family members, are not capitalist). The only reason
|
||
workers want to be employed by capitalists is because they have
|
||
no other means for making a living, no access to the means of
|
||
production other than by selling themselves. For a capitalist
|
||
sector to exist there must be some form of private ownership of
|
||
productive resources, and a scarcity of alternatives. The workers
|
||
must be in a condition of economic desperation for them to be
|
||
willing to give up an equal voice in the management of their
|
||
daily affairs and accept a boss. Wage labor would not be
|
||
tolerated in an anarchist society anymore than extortion or
|
||
blackmail, no matter how much the perpetrator might claim the
|
||
victims "asked for it." It would not take any "coercion" to get
|
||
rid of wage labor either, as long as the condition for possession
|
||
of any productive property is that all workers be given an equal
|
||
voice in management. If not, the facility in question is given to
|
||
some other group that will run things democratically.
|
||
To the extent that A Structured Anarchism was meant to stir
|
||
controversy, it has succeeded. If it was meant to lay the
|
||
foundation for a more practical anarchist economic alternative,
|
||
it is a botched attempt. Griffin's "collectivism" might more
|
||
accurately be described as watered down mutualism mixed with
|
||
laissez faire liberal ideology.
|
||
|
||
Recent Books on Spanish Anarchism
|
||
|
||
Reviewed by Jon Bekken
|
||
|
||
Anarchist Ideology and the Working-Class Movement in Spain, 1868-
|
||
1898 by George Esenwein. University of California Press (Berkeley
|
||
CA 94720), 1989.
|
||
Esenwein offers a rare English-language look at the origins
|
||
of the Spanish anarchist movement. He argues against the
|
||
"millenarian" approach (viewing anarchist as a prepolitical,
|
||
incoherent movement almost religious in its emotional appeal)
|
||
that dominated academic research into Spanish anarchism until
|
||
fairly recently, instead focusing his attention on the evolution
|
||
of movement ideology from the September Revolution of 1868
|
||
through the aftermath of the Montjuich repression, which forced
|
||
our comrades underground.
|
||
Esenwein situates Spanish anarchism in working-class
|
||
associational life, and anarchist ideology within broader
|
||
theoretical debates in the European socialist movement,
|
||
demonstrating that anarchist ideas gained substantial influence
|
||
within only two years of their introduction. The anarchists
|
||
plastered street corners with revolutionary manifestos and
|
||
published newspapers and pamphlets to spread their ideas
|
||
throughout the country, reading them aloud for those who could
|
||
not read. The movement quickly developed its own holidays and
|
||
cultural traditions. Each November 11th, for example, Spanish
|
||
anarchists commemorated the Haymarket martyrs and others fallen
|
||
in the struggle against capital and the state. Commemorative
|
||
meetings were largely devoted to readings of prose and poetry
|
||
dedicated to their memory, and to revolutionary songs. Like the
|
||
anarchists' May Day demonstrations, these meetings aimed less at
|
||
mourning the dead than on continuing and expanding the
|
||
revolutionary struggle.
|
||
Anarchist ideas focussing on direct action, class struggle
|
||
and revolution, quickly came to dominate the Spanish labor press.
|
||
Although the Marxists eventually built their own organizations,
|
||
they were far less influential. Esenwein demonstrates that even
|
||
though he never set foot in the country, Bakunin was deeply
|
||
involved in organizing the Spanish movement through
|
||
correspondence and the brotherhood of his comrades. "Beyond
|
||
doubt[,] their adherence to Bakunin's program contributed greatly
|
||
to the FRE's ability to flourish... and to survive the harsh
|
||
circumstances of repression" (p. 224, n. 15).
|
||
The Spanish movement was shaped in adversity, often forced
|
||
to go underground to survive repression. The Federation was
|
||
outlawed between 1874 and 1881, encouraging a turn from strikes
|
||
and other mass direct action to individual acts of "propaganda by
|
||
the deed." This, in turn, provided a pretext for further
|
||
repression against workers' movements. The anarcho-syndicalist
|
||
movement developed during this underground period, seeking a way
|
||
out of an increasingly tenuous illegal status while maintaining
|
||
their revolutionary values. Esenwein chronicles the debate
|
||
between collectivist and communist currents, and the eventual
|
||
triumph of 'anarquismo sin adjectivos,' an attempt to sidestep
|
||
the entire debate in favor of an all-inclusive movement.
|
||
Spanish syndicalism developed out of this tendency, quickly
|
||
coming to dominate the anarchist movement. It was only with the
|
||
emergence of the CNT, Esenwein argues, that anarchism developed a
|
||
mass following among the working-class. But in the latter quarter
|
||
of the 19th century, anarchists developed the ideas and
|
||
organizational forms that "enabled [them] to combine successfully
|
||
trade unionism with the general strike tactic... [making]
|
||
anarchism a formidable social and economic force in a rapidly
|
||
modernizing Spanish society" (p. 215).
|
||
Esenwein relies heavily on secondary sources and memoirs,
|
||
making relatively little use of movement newspapers and other
|
||
contemporary sources (perhaps not held at the Hoover Institute,
|
||
where he is employed). Nonetheless, his extensive endnotes are
|
||
often informative and correct much misinformation spread by less
|
||
careful historians of our movement (even if he is too quick to
|
||
accept Jos<6F> S<>nchez's weakly documented claims of anarchist
|
||
atrocities during the Spanish Revolution). While Esenwein is
|
||
clearly no anarchist, it is difficult to argue with Paul Avrich's
|
||
assessment (printed on the back cover) that this is "an
|
||
outstanding history of Spanish anarchism during its formative
|
||
decades in the late nineteenth century... the best treatment of
|
||
the subject in English."
|
||
|
||
Spain 1936-1939: Social Revolution--Counter Revolution, edited by
|
||
Vernon Richards. Freedom Press, 1990.
|
||
This volume, released as part of Freedom Press' centenary
|
||
series, brings together 75 short texts, most originally published
|
||
in the journal Spain and the World. The selections include first-
|
||
hand accounts of the revolution, reports on meetings and
|
||
demonstrations in favor of the Spanish workers' struggle, reports
|
||
of speeches by CNT and FAI figures justifying their compromises
|
||
in accepting government posts, testimonials by non-anarchists on
|
||
the constructive work carried out by our comrades in society and
|
||
on the battlefield, and two poems by Herbert Read.
|
||
This volume is not a history of the Revolution, rather it is
|
||
composed of reports from the front written in the heat of battle.
|
||
As such, they provide invaluable contemporary glimpses into
|
||
various facets of our Spanish comrades' struggle, though not
|
||
always the depth and detail we might prefer, especially in the
|
||
material on the collectives. (Fortunately, Freedom Press also
|
||
offers Gaston Leval's detailed Collectives in the Spanish
|
||
Revolution, Jose Peirats' Anarchists in the Spanish Revolution, a
|
||
detailed report by A. Souchy and others on The May Days:
|
||
Barcelona 1937, and Vernon Richards' controversial Lessons of the
|
||
Spanish Revolution. Interested readers may also want to look at
|
||
Sam Dolgoff's collection, The Anarchist Collectives: Workers'
|
||
Self-Management in Spain, published by Black Rose Books, and
|
||
David Porter's moving anthology of writings by Emma Goldman,
|
||
Vision on Fire.) Very little of the material in this collection
|
||
comes from the Revolution's early months, for the simple reason
|
||
that Spain and the World did not begin publication until
|
||
November, 1936. So this is almost entirely a chronicle of a
|
||
revolution under attack, both by the fascists and by its allies--
|
||
the socialists, republicans and, above all, the communists.
|
||
Although readers unfamiliar with the Spanish Revolution
|
||
would do better to begin with one of the books mentioned above,
|
||
this is a useful supplementary volume. Particularly interesting
|
||
are the brief portraits of several anarchist militants, Italian
|
||
anarchist Camillo Berneri's views on the dangers posed by the
|
||
compromises the anarchists made with their Marxist "allies" (who
|
||
never honored them), and reports on Spain's ultimate collapse and
|
||
the appalling treatment of Spanish refugees at the hands of the
|
||
French Popular Front government.
|
||
In Spain our comrades demonstrated that anarchism not only
|
||
offers a powerful critique of authoritarianism, but more
|
||
importantly that it offers a strategy for reorganizing society
|
||
along libertarian lines. That they were ultimately defeated is no
|
||
disgrace--what was disgraceful was the treachery of the
|
||
"democratic" governments, marxists, and others of their ilk who
|
||
demonstrated that they preferred the triumph of fascism in Spain
|
||
to a workers' revolution.
|
||
|
||
Reviewed Briefly
|
||
Winning the Class War: an Anarcho-Syndicalist Strategy by the
|
||
Direct Action Movement. DAM (Box 29, SW PDO, Manchester 15,
|
||
U.K.), 1991, 28 pp.
|
||
This pamphlet, published by the Direct Action Movement, the
|
||
British affiliate of the IWA, makes the case that the British
|
||
trade unions have generally hindered workers' efforts to defend
|
||
their living standards from the onslaught of the employers during
|
||
the Thatcher era. This is not because, as the various Marxist
|
||
sects argue, of the ineptitude of the trade union leadership, but
|
||
because the trade unions have been designed to be "an important
|
||
part of capitalism." Instead, the DAM advocates the organization
|
||
of "a new and altogether independent workers' movement...
|
||
revolutionary unionism" with "the aim of creating a free and
|
||
classless society, based on workers' control and the satisfaction
|
||
of human needs" (p. 4).
|
||
Winning the Class War signifies a departure for British
|
||
syndicalism. At the turn of the century, British syndicalists
|
||
(with the exception of a tiny British IWW section) generally
|
||
followed the practice of trying to revolutionize the Trades Union
|
||
Congress by "boring from within." The present generation,
|
||
however, argues that clearly the TUC has had its day, and that
|
||
the left-wing tradition of "rank-and-filism" (i.e., the old "bore
|
||
from within" strategy of trying to reform the trade unions)
|
||
proved to be a dismal failure during the 1980s. Parts of Winning
|
||
the Class War read almost as if they came from the IWW's One Big
|
||
Union pamphlet. For instance, on page 4, the DAM clearly argues
|
||
for the One Big Union concept: "The working class needs to take
|
||
stock of the new situation in which it finds itself, and needs to
|
||
organize itself as a class if it is to fight for its interests
|
||
against the bosses."
|
||
Faced with the problem of organizing a revolutionary union
|
||
movement from scratch, the DAM does not suggest building them
|
||
overnight, but building "industrial networks" as a first step.
|
||
The DAM makes an important distinction between industrial
|
||
networks and "rank-and-filism." Industrial networks "maintain
|
||
their independence and identity" from the trade unions by
|
||
encouraging "general workplace activity ie. workplace meetings,
|
||
strike committees, etc, outside of the sphere of influence of the
|
||
unions and other 'interested' bodies, like the political parties"
|
||
and have as their ultimate aim not trade union reform, but "to
|
||
create an anarcho-syndicalist union" (p. 19).
|
||
The most historically successful of all syndicalist
|
||
movements, the Spanish CNT, combined the best elements of
|
||
anarcho-syndicalism and the IWW's "revolutionary industrial
|
||
unionism." The British syndicalists have clearly begun to
|
||
recognize this fact, and are now seeking to apply the lesson to
|
||
their own conditions. This makes Winning the Class War a
|
||
worthwhile pamphlet to read for workers in any country. [JS]
|
||
|
||
Mapping Hegemony: Television News Coverage of Industrial Conflict
|
||
by Robert Goldman and Arvind Rajagopal. Ablex (355 Chestnut St.,
|
||
Norwood NJ 07648-2090), 1991, 258 pp.
|
||
Goldman and Rajagopal examine the ways in which television
|
||
newscasters shape public understandings by scrutinizing CBS News
|
||
coverage of the 1977-78 coal miners' strike. The analysis is
|
||
presented in terms of an ongoing sociological debates around
|
||
ideology and hegemony (which attempts to explain how particular
|
||
ideas, such as the notion that workers are a special interest,
|
||
come to be widely accepted as common sense), which makes for some
|
||
rather difficult slogging in the early chapters. As the authors
|
||
note, the media rarely report on labor issues except in the
|
||
context of strikes and violence. The media show little interest
|
||
in working conditions, health and safety, or routine labor
|
||
struggles.
|
||
The authors have looked at every report aired on the strike
|
||
on CBS News to examine how CBS portrayed mine workers, the union,
|
||
the government and the bosses. To illustrate how these portrayals
|
||
represent choices--rather than some objective picture of events--
|
||
they also examine coverage in local and other newspapers. The
|
||
strike stemmed from efforts by miners to gain control over their
|
||
union, gain relief for black lung victims, defend their embattled
|
||
health care system, and reverse a long-term decline in union
|
||
power. In the 1970s, miners increasingly resorted to wildcat
|
||
strikes over health and safety and other issues (the courts, of
|
||
course, regularly issued back-to-work injunctions even though the
|
||
miners had never signed a no-strike agreement). The operators,
|
||
meanwhile, demanded the right to fire strikers, to slash health
|
||
benefits, etc. After miners rejected a sell-out contract,
|
||
Democratic president Jimmy Carter issued a Taft-Hartley
|
||
injunction to force them back to work. But fewer than 100 of
|
||
160,000 strikers obeyed the order.
|
||
CBS aired several pictures of angry miners throughout the
|
||
dispute, but rarely reported why miners were upset or what they
|
||
wanted. The network did give as much air time to miners and the
|
||
UMW as to the coal operators association and the government, but
|
||
this was because the operators preferred to keep a low profile
|
||
and so generally refused comment. (Indeed, the bosses were
|
||
virtually invisible on CBS--workers went on strike, workers
|
||
defied the government, workers threatened the nation's energy
|
||
supply, etc.) And miners were rarely allowed more than a few
|
||
seconds to make their case, were shown in tight close-ups in off-
|
||
the-cuff settings. Rank-and-file miners appeared in interviews
|
||
averaging just 9 seconds, while UMW, industry and government
|
||
officials averaged 15-20 seconds per interview. It is, of course,
|
||
easier to express coherent, compelling arguments in 20 seconds
|
||
(and Carter once got more than 2 minutes) than in "interviews"
|
||
ranging from 2 to 16 seconds long.
|
||
"Though ostensibly impartial on the surface, the terms of
|
||
presenting the issues have been stacked to privilege the
|
||
interests of capital.... The neutrality the news media seek
|
||
consists not in a bias toward any particular fraction of capital,
|
||
but in depending on, accepting and promoting the interests of
|
||
capital in general" (177). Although CBS did several human
|
||
interest stories on the miners themselves that may have increased
|
||
public sympathy, it never allowed them to speak about the
|
||
underlying issues. Network coverage created "balance" by
|
||
portraying strikers in a battle not against the bosses, but
|
||
against the public (and against their union). Government
|
||
intervention against the miners, then, is shown as necessary and
|
||
inevitable. While miners were shown, their story was not told--
|
||
and indeed cannot be told within the constraints of journalists'
|
||
ideas as to what constitutes news, whose ideas are newsworthy,
|
||
and how information should be presented.
|
||
Not all viewers necessarily make the same interpretations of
|
||
the reports they see, of course. But Goldman and Rajagopal argue
|
||
that while it is theoretically possible to read these reports in
|
||
any number of ways (such as, for example, as evidence of anti-
|
||
labor media bias), certain meanings are preferred, and more
|
||
readily available to audiences. I suspect that had Goldman and
|
||
Rajagopal looked at a more recent dispute, they would have found
|
||
much more one-sided coverage (and also much less coverage--labor
|
||
has practically disappeared from the news, and even presidential
|
||
candidates today are rarely given more than a few seconds to
|
||
spread their lies). But they have done a thorough job of
|
||
demonstrating just how the patterns of media coverage (which
|
||
pervade all news) serve to refocus, distort and mislead--even as
|
||
journalists proclaim and believe that they are objective and
|
||
unbiased. [JB]
|
||
|
||
Not Beyond Repair : Reflections of a Malaysian Trade Unionist by
|
||
Arokia Dass. Asia Monitor Resource Center (444-446 Nathan Road,
|
||
8-B Kowloon, Hong Kong), 1991. 177 pp., $14.50.
|
||
|
||
Arokia Dass, a former rank-and-file insurgent and presently
|
||
an official of the Malaysian autoworkers' union, gives a history
|
||
of the Malaysian labor movement. Dass is critical of the labor
|
||
unions in his country for being bureaucratic and dominated by the
|
||
state and the employers. He also accuses the ICFTU, the AIFLD,
|
||
and the Japanese unions, with being pro-employer and undermining
|
||
militant unions in other countries. The author suggests that the
|
||
solutions to the problems of Malaysian labor are more shop-floor
|
||
union democracy, direct worker-to-worker contacts between
|
||
countries, and a labor party.
|
||
Although Dass is clearly a marxist, he suggests that marxism
|
||
is as much in need of repair as trade unionism. He demonstrates
|
||
that marxist analysis does not fully explain the labor situation
|
||
in Asia, where capitalism and the state can at times have
|
||
conflicting agendas, and strongly rooted cultural traditions
|
||
provide an added political dimension. Unfortunately, this does
|
||
not prevent him from aligning himself with the communist-
|
||
dominated WFTU, which he claims is an international center "free
|
||
from political ideology," nor from apologizing for the failures
|
||
of central economic planning in eastern europe.
|
||
In spite of the author's ideological blinders, there is some
|
||
interesting information in this book. The role of labor
|
||
regulation and selective repression of radical unionists in
|
||
creating a docile labor movement is explained very well. Dass
|
||
also shows how workers have been betrayed on numerous occasions
|
||
by nationalist politicians, who are unwilling or incapable of
|
||
providing effective resistance to multinational corporations.
|
||
[JS]
|
||
|
||
From The Ground Up: Essays on Grassroots & Workplace Democracy,
|
||
by C. George Benello. Edited by Len Krimmerman, Frank Lindenfeld,
|
||
Carol Korty and Julian Benello. South End Press (116 St. Botolph
|
||
St., Boston MA 02115) $12.00.
|
||
George Benello was an anarchist of sorts, active in the New
|
||
Left and then the workplace-democracy, peace and green movements.
|
||
He was part of an American decentralist movement that included
|
||
Paul Goodman, Lewis Mumford, Ralph Bosordi and others often
|
||
mistakenly labelled as anarchists (though there certainly are
|
||
similarities and borrowings to and from). Towards the end of his
|
||
life, Benello wrote a series of essays in the "Libertarian
|
||
Municipalist" tradition which are the book's weakest, and which
|
||
he never published during his lifetime--perhaps because he
|
||
recognized their many contradictions.
|
||
In these essays, Benello criticizes the "wasteland culture"
|
||
and attempts to articulate a strategy for confronting a system
|
||
that "works all too well [writing in 1967], and in the process
|
||
grinds up human beings" (p. 20). Although it is easier and more
|
||
efficient, in the short run, to organize hierarchically, Benello
|
||
argued, such social arrangements are undemocratic, deny people
|
||
the ability to realize their potential, and ensure that basic
|
||
social needs will go unmet since elites need not take them into
|
||
consideration. Many of the early essays in this collection
|
||
address aspects of participatory democracy and federalism, and
|
||
how these might be realized in practice:
|
||
A movement striving to bring to life viable and
|
||
effective models of humanized work, capable of creating
|
||
useful and consumer-oriented products while utilizing a
|
||
high level of technology, would strike at the heart of
|
||
the corporate system... It could appeal to the new
|
||
consumer and ecological consciousness... to the growing
|
||
group of unemployed or those employed in positions
|
||
below their skill and education level. ... A movement
|
||
creating not only jobs ut also self-determination and
|
||
freedom in work, committed to producing goods with
|
||
integrity and usefulness, would not only appeal to
|
||
basic material needs, but would also provide a live
|
||
basis from which a critique of both the dehumanization
|
||
of work and the falseness of current consumer values
|
||
could be made... (p. 85)
|
||
Benello pursued this objective, for the most part, through
|
||
efforts to create self-managed enterprises which he saw as a
|
||
means both of meeting real needs and of demonstrating the
|
||
viability of democracy in actual practice--an issue which is
|
||
addressed in several of the essays reprinted here. Those essays
|
||
discuss self-management as both an objective to be struggled for
|
||
and a means of struggle whereby workers can educate themselves in
|
||
the skills necessary for a democratic economy while carving out a
|
||
space relatively autonomous from capitalist relations. Benello
|
||
considers the role that unions might play in such worker-
|
||
controlled enterprises, offers his take on the Mondragon network
|
||
and the lessons it can offer North American workers, and provides
|
||
useful (if brief) reflections on his involvement in the
|
||
Federation for Economic Democracy and the Industrial Cooperative
|
||
Association. These essays are among the collection's strongest.
|
||
Unfortunately, the editors proceed to include essays on the
|
||
"decentralist" potential Benello saw in nuclear free zones and
|
||
efforts to develop local tax and economic policies reminiscent of
|
||
Bookchin's libertarian municipalism. To his credit, Benello did
|
||
not publish these no-doubt exploratory writings. The book
|
||
concludes with commentaries on Benello's thought, some of which
|
||
implicitly or explicitly defend centralism and hierarchy, or
|
||
argue for working "within the system." The editors conclude with
|
||
an essay reasserting the importance of Benello's thought in terms
|
||
far less cogent than those advanced by Benello himself. [JB]
|
||
|
||
Freedom to Go: After the Motor Age by Colin Ward. Freedom Press
|
||
(Angel Alley , 84b Whitechapel High Street, London E1 7QX), 1991.
|
||
112 pp., 3.50 pounds.
|
||
|
||
Colin Ward points out that our dependence on the private
|
||
automobile makes the freedom to travel an illusion. People do not
|
||
choose to travel by car from a variety of alternatives, since
|
||
those alternatives are rarely there. Government transportation
|
||
planners and corporate investors have foisted the automobile upon
|
||
us. More energy efficient, less dangerous, and less
|
||
environmentally damaging forms of transport, like rail or boat,
|
||
have been starved for investment, while billions are spent on
|
||
highways.
|
||
Ward stops short of suggesting that only by doing away with
|
||
a profit-oriented transportation system can we go beyond the
|
||
automobile age. Rather he ends by offering some reforms which
|
||
"people of any political complexion can agree with." These
|
||
include a moratorium on new road construction, greater railway
|
||
investment, low-cost or free mass transit, traffic limits in
|
||
towns, and minibus cooperatives for rural areas. Freedom to Go is
|
||
a well-written primer for anyone interested in transportation
|
||
alternatives. [JS]
|
||
|
||
Reweaving the World: The Emergence of Ecofeminism, edited by
|
||
Irene Diamond and Gloria Feman Orenstein. Sierra Club Books (730
|
||
Polk St., San Francisco CA 94109) $14.95.
|
||
This curious anthology brings together 26 essays that,
|
||
despite the all-embracing title, are drawn from a very
|
||
particular, spiritualist, current within ecofeminism. As a
|
||
result, most of the book reads more like a theological than a
|
||
political text. In this context, reformists like Charlene
|
||
Spretnak and mystics like Starhawk are among a very few authors
|
||
who seek to come to grips with the actual, material conditions
|
||
that are destroying our planet and our humanity.
|
||
Spretnak raises the question of power, arguing for the
|
||
importance of improving health and economic conditions and
|
||
involving "women at the regional level... with the planning of
|
||
population-control programs, health care, education, and non-
|
||
exploitative small-scale economic opportunities" (p. 12). This
|
||
may not seem, and is not, particularly far-reaching. But it is a
|
||
refreshing contrast to such nonsense as: "in ancient times the
|
||
world itself was one. The beating of drums was the heartbeat of
|
||
the earth.... everything was done in a sacred manner..." (p. 33)
|
||
Starhawk's essay, "Power, Authority and Mystery" argues for
|
||
an "earth-based spirituality" grounded in the interconnectedness
|
||
of the earth. She analyzes the Livermore Action Group's campaign
|
||
against the U.S. weapons lab; discusses the need to address
|
||
questions of sex, class and race; and argues that we must reject
|
||
apocalyptic rhetoric in favor of approaches that allow for hope,
|
||
for human agency, for organizing. Her analytic metaphor is
|
||
grounded in the economy, which, she argues, "reflects our system
|
||
of values, in which profit replaces inherent value as the
|
||
ultimate measure of all things." If the "anarcho-pagans" invading
|
||
our movement in recent years thought as sensibly it might be
|
||
possible to work with them.
|
||
Other worthwhile essays include those by Ynestra King and
|
||
Vandana Shiva ("Development as a New Project of Western
|
||
Patriarchy"). But while the book may prove useful for those
|
||
trying to get a handle on the gibberish spouted by many new-age
|
||
"ecologists" and "anarchists," those seriously interested in
|
||
reweaving the world would do better to look elsewhere. [JB]
|
||
|
||
Work, Politics and Power: An International Perspective on
|
||
Workers' Control and Self-Management, by Assef Bayat. Monthly
|
||
Review Press (122 W. 27th St., New York NY 10001), 1991, $18
|
||
(paper).
|
||
Too often, the literature on self-management assumes that
|
||
only in advanced capitalist societies can workers aspire to
|
||
exercise control of the production process. Bayat argues that
|
||
experiments with democracy in the workplace are a central part of
|
||
workers' asserting their humanity and transcending meaningless
|
||
work, and that such democratization is possible even in Third
|
||
World settings. In this, he is surely correct. However, Bayat's
|
||
argument is undermined by a fairly doctrinaire Marxist approach
|
||
and by his often superficial descriptions (drawn almost entirely
|
||
from previous studies, the details of which he only rarely
|
||
provides) of the experiments in "workers' control" that he
|
||
discusses and compares.
|
||
Bayat does recognize the importance of power relations in
|
||
industry, noting that a mere transfer of ownership is not
|
||
sufficient to overcome the powerlessness intrinsic in existing
|
||
work methods, technologies, and separation of technical expertise
|
||
from the shop floor. Ultimately, this requires a transition from
|
||
private to social ownership, Bayat argues, although workers can
|
||
gain some control even in the context of capitalist societies.
|
||
His definition of workers' control is wide-ranging, from
|
||
defensive struggles to maintain conditions to efforts to seize
|
||
direction of the enterprise. It includes both rank-and-file
|
||
efforts and strategies where employers or the State grant limited
|
||
"control" or participation rights in order to defuse broader
|
||
demands. The bulk of the case studies Bayat considers fall in the
|
||
latter category.
|
||
Bayat divides his many case studies into three categories:
|
||
conditions of dual power (Russia, Algeria, Chile, Portugal and
|
||
Iran), socialist states (China, Cuba, Mozambique and Nicaragua),
|
||
and populist regimes (Egypt, Tanzania, Peru and Turkey). For
|
||
those less wedded to Marxist doctrine, the distinction between
|
||
the latter categories ("populism here denotes the nationalistic
|
||
ideology and development strategy of a regime which relies on the
|
||
support of the popular classes [workers, peasants and 'the poor']
|
||
as its social base, while it pursues a capitalistic economic
|
||
policy within the framework of an authoritarian state" p. 130)
|
||
will be unclear at best. Thus we see the unlikely prospect of a
|
||
discussion of "workers' control" in Cuba during the very period
|
||
that the government was ruthlessly suppressing all independent
|
||
working-class organizations, or of "workers' control" in
|
||
Nicaragua at a time when co-operatives and unions were subject to
|
||
government registration and approval, and were prohibited from
|
||
criticizing the government or demanding better pay and working
|
||
conditions.
|
||
Bayat brings together a great deal of information on
|
||
participation schemes in several countries, but these are often
|
||
more akin to quality-of-worklife programs introduced by union-
|
||
busting employers in the U.S. than to genuine self-management.
|
||
Nonetheless, he demonstrates the very real desire by our "Third
|
||
World" fellow workers in countries throughout the entire world to
|
||
control their workplaces and their worklives. This surely gives
|
||
us reason to hope, and indicates that the bosses' current global
|
||
offensive may well ultimately meet with defeat. [JB]
|
||
|
||
Strip the Experts by Brian Martin. Freedom Press (in Angel Alley,
|
||
84b Whitechapel High Street, London, E1 7QX), 1991. 69 pp., 1.95
|
||
pounds.
|
||
|
||
This is a humorous how-to manual for anyone engaged in a
|
||
propaganda campaign where the other side has all the "hired guns"
|
||
(ie. academics, well-known professionals, etc.) to convince the
|
||
public they have a monopoly on the truth. Martin shows how to go
|
||
about discrediting the "experts," although sometimes his value-
|
||
free approach can be disturbing. For example, Martin's main
|
||
reason for arguing against character assassination seems to be
|
||
that such tactics might "backfire," not that they should be
|
||
avoided on principle. [JS]
|
||
|
||
CORRECTION
|
||
Our review of The Anarchist Press in LLR #12 stated that
|
||
Love & Rage had "eliminated much of the nationalist cheerleading
|
||
that marred its early issues.... [and] is no longer an
|
||
embarrassment to our movement." After those words were written,
|
||
but before we went to press, they published an untrue account of
|
||
the IWW's 1991 assembly including groundless accusations against
|
||
a member of our collective (refusing to publish his response).
|
||
More recently, they published a lengthy article celebrating Black
|
||
nationalism. Thus, it appears that our relief may have been
|
||
premature.
|
||
|