135 lines
8.6 KiB
Plaintext
135 lines
8.6 KiB
Plaintext
|
|
REGARDING Book Review: Liability
|
|
|
|
If you have read Peter Huber's recent _Galileo's Revenge_, or Walter Olson's
|
|
_The Litigation Explosion_, or if you've been following some of the recent
|
|
pushes for legal reform (spearheaded by Quayle???), or if you're like me and
|
|
you like watching "L.A. Law" just because you know you're going to disagree
|
|
with most of the cases they keep on winning all the time, or if you've heard
|
|
the joke where the lawyer is talking to someone on the street and an ambulance
|
|
speeds by and he suddenly says, "Sorry, gotta run!", then you may be interested
|
|
in Peter Huber's first book on legal reform, _Liability_.
|
|
|
|
Peter Huber; _Liability: The Legal Revolution and its Consequences_; 1988;
|
|
Basic Books; 260 pages.
|
|
|
|
Peter Huber's _Liability_ is an intellectual history of the long, slippery
|
|
slope that is recent tort law. The strength of Huber's book lies in quickly
|
|
identifying a central fallacious judicial policy and then tracing its history
|
|
of unforeseen consequences and inverted logic from the late 50's up to the
|
|
present time. It's extremely well written, so it lends itself to a quick
|
|
summary.
|
|
|
|
The problem started when a group of "progressive" judges and legal scholars
|
|
determined that consumers don't take risk into account adequately and fail to
|
|
demand sufficient safety from products. The courts adopted a progressively
|
|
hostile attitude towards producers, applying arbitrary standards of risk to all
|
|
products, regardless of individual preferences expressed in the form of a
|
|
contract. The courts did this in order to force producers to be more careful,
|
|
to provide consumers with a kind of secondary insurance, and to create a hidden
|
|
tax on unsafe products. According to this philosophy, it didn't really matter
|
|
if the product caused the injury, what mattered was that producers take
|
|
responsibility for the percentage of accidents that inevitably result from its
|
|
use. Don't blame whoever was at fault, blame whoever could have avoided the
|
|
accident at the lowest cost, the one with the deepest pockets.
|
|
|
|
For these goals to be achieved, many legal standards had to erode. The very
|
|
sanctity of contracts came into question, and contract law rapidly yielded to
|
|
more contentious torts. If you didn't specifically warn against the risk of
|
|
heart palpitations when selling "happy fun ball," a broad disclaimer was
|
|
nullified. If you counter by putting in specific warnings, courts would counter
|
|
by saying the warning wasn't conspicuously placed even if it was in the
|
|
contract, that the contract was not negotiated properly, that the producer
|
|
violated an unrelated minor point of the contract, that one of the parties
|
|
wasn't competent to enter into the contract with the big bad corporation--what
|
|
we tend to call "loopholes" when the results are not so auspicious.
|
|
|
|
The standards for ordinary prudence and negligence also shifted. Courts that
|
|
previously had only ruled on manufacturing defects (a single item from the
|
|
assembly line) now ruled mainly on design defects (the entire production run).
|
|
A "design defect" is a vague concept, and juries got into the business of
|
|
rearranging priorities and second-guessing engineers. If you received an injury
|
|
from operating a Yugo that may have been prevented if it were designed more
|
|
like a Volvo, that can construed as a design defect. The fact that you
|
|
expressed a preference for the cheaper, riskier car does not matter, since
|
|
consumers are assumed to be innocent and ignorant of safety information when
|
|
entering into the bargain. Some products, such as effective drugs, are
|
|
inherently risky, and juries started drawing comparisons between existing
|
|
products and hypothetical, ideal products. Although regulatory agencies and
|
|
trade associations are no doubt more knowledgeable in developing standards,
|
|
judges and juries regularly subvert those standards in order to make them
|
|
arbitrarily more strict. [To be fair, at least the courts were efficient in
|
|
making their decisions and left a fairly clean wound, unlike regulatory
|
|
agencies, which require large bureaucracies to arrive at their arbitrary
|
|
decisions. :>) ] Still, manufacturers have little way to determine what the
|
|
"law" really is, or is going to be tomorrow, so they adopt a policy of extreme
|
|
defensiveness, often withholding potentially valuable products and services
|
|
from the market.
|
|
|
|
Under the new liberal rules, the statute of limitations was loosened and then
|
|
dispensed with. Discovery rules were changed so that it didn't matter when the
|
|
injury took place; when you discovered it many years later you were still
|
|
entitled to sue, when the defendant's ability to gather evidence or even
|
|
remember who you are is sharply reduced. Plaintiffs sued in anticipation of
|
|
injuries that may not actually have occurred, but for which a plausible case
|
|
could be made that they would at some point. Once plausibility broke down,
|
|
cases rested on unsupported fears of future harm, fear being considered itself
|
|
an injury. The link between cause and effect was severely eroded when any
|
|
"scientist" willing to be an "expert witness" could promulgate quack theories.
|
|
[This aspect of the problem is dealt with comprehensively in Huber's follow-up
|
|
book, _Galileo's Revenge_.]
|
|
|
|
At the end of all this activism, life is made no less risky. Huber uses the
|
|
example of a cole slaw machine in which you put pieces of cabbage in an opening
|
|
at one end and cole slaw comes out the other end. Suppose a child's hand is
|
|
caught in the machine one day. The court determines that the opening was too
|
|
wide to be safe, and insists that it be made narrow. Fine. Now, for the
|
|
cabbage to fit through the opening, the chunks have to be smaller, and for that
|
|
you have to use a knife, which is at least as likely to cause injury. But what
|
|
are you going to do, sue the manufacturer of the knife for your clumsiness? So
|
|
the net result is not that risk is reduced, but that the specific behavior that
|
|
gets people sued is reduced or diverted. New technologies suffer
|
|
disproportionately.
|
|
|
|
The tragic consequences of flexible liability can be seen in its effects upon
|
|
health care. Medical services become so expensive as a result of the
|
|
exorbitant malpractice insurance rates and entry barriers to decent health care
|
|
are so high that calls are made for drastic measures, such as universal health
|
|
care and no-fault insurance, that hide costs and diffuse individual
|
|
responsibility. On the one hand you can say that flexible liability is more
|
|
effective in preventing dangerous products from ever coming to market. The
|
|
reality, though, is that the first products that are selected against are those
|
|
high-risk products that people need most, such as vaccines and birth control
|
|
devices.
|
|
|
|
This condensation cannot convey how reasonable the logic sounds at each point
|
|
as it goes by, even if you haven't consciously accepted the initial assumption
|
|
that producers implicitly accept responsibility for all damages. Many of the
|
|
plaintiffs described in the book were no doubt wronged on some level, and
|
|
indeed deserving, but the book steps back and examines the legal seduction that
|
|
was necessary to entertain these cases in the first place. Often Huber's tone
|
|
makes it seem as if the judges and lawyers destroyed legal standards
|
|
consciously, for the hell of it. Of course, the truth is far worse-- they
|
|
genuinely wanted to do good.
|
|
|
|
Huber is very good at digging a hole and leading us down into legal hell, but
|
|
not as good leading us out of it. I found his "What's Wrong" section far more
|
|
convincing than his "What We Can Do About It" section, and you'll sympathize
|
|
with such pessimism by the time you reach the end of the book. Huber calls for
|
|
a resurgence of contract law, not the primitive sort of catch-all disclaimers
|
|
that existed before tort law took over, but flexible agreements that take
|
|
consumers' advanced expectations into account. Interestingly, Huber implicitly
|
|
bases his argument on the idea that the "market" for contracts initially failed
|
|
to take new consumer expectations into account, resulting in a takeover by the Judiciary.
|
|
If there was an inherent weakness in the market that led to such government
|
|
zealousness, then what caused it, and how might the mistaken policy have been
|
|
avoided in the first place?
|
|
|
|
Unlike Walter Olson's _The Litigation Explosion_, Huber does not spend much
|
|
time describing the symptoms-- a society permeated with ambulance-chasers. I
|
|
suspect that Olson's book is more likely to be useful if you are interested in
|
|
specific reforms. Huber's book is a short history of ideas that will help you
|
|
understand how we got to this point.
|
|
|
|
Downloaded From P-80 International Information Systems 304-744-2253
|