491 lines
28 KiB
Plaintext
491 lines
28 KiB
Plaintext
|
Libertarian Labor Review #13
|
||
|
Summer 1992, pages 24-29
|
||
|
|
||
|
THE COLLECTIVIST TRANSITION
|
||
|
by Jeff Stein
|
||
|
|
||
|
Introduction: Anarchist economics began with Proudhon but
|
||
|
eventually developed into two schools of thought: anarcho-
|
||
|
syndicalism with its emphasis on mass production industries in an
|
||
|
urban environment, and anarchist-communism with its emphasis on
|
||
|
egalitarian distribution and small-scale communities. Both these
|
||
|
theories developed out of anarcho-collectivism, a radical economic
|
||
|
federalism developed by the libertarian elements of the (First)
|
||
|
International Workingmen's Association. Its principal advocates
|
||
|
were Michael Bakunin and James Guillaume, but the real credit for
|
||
|
the theory of collectivism should go to the workers belonging to
|
||
|
the International, who took the various socialist and trade union
|
||
|
economic ideas of the time and modified them in light of their own
|
||
|
experience.
|
||
|
|
||
|
The Limits of Proudhonian Economics
|
||
|
The collectivists shared a number of ideas with the followers
|
||
|
of Proudhon in the International, in particular the concepts of
|
||
|
workers self-management of industry and economic federalism. On the
|
||
|
other hand they saw a need to go beyond the sort of utopian
|
||
|
thinking that led the Proudhonists to believe capitalism might be
|
||
|
transformed by the growth of worker cooperatives and mutualist
|
||
|
credit. By the time the International was formed in 1864, worker
|
||
|
cooperatives had been experimented with for several decades and by
|
||
|
now were floundering. In the last years of his life, even Proudhon
|
||
|
was forced to admit the cooperative movement was not developing as
|
||
|
he had hoped:
|
||
|
Not many years later, in 1857, he severely criticized the
|
||
|
existing workers' associations; inspired by naive,
|
||
|
utopian illusions, they had paid the price of their lack
|
||
|
of experience. They had become narrow and exclusive, had
|
||
|
functioned as collective employers, and had been carried
|
||
|
away by hierarchical and managerial concepts. All the
|
||
|
abuses of capitalist companies "were exaggerated further
|
||
|
in these so-called brotherhoods." They had been torn by
|
||
|
discord, rivalry, defections, and betrayals. Once their
|
||
|
managers had learned the business concerned, they retired
|
||
|
to "set up as bourgeois employers on their own account."
|
||
|
In other instances, the members had insisted on dividing
|
||
|
up the resources. In 1848 several hundred workers'
|
||
|
associations had been set up; nine years later only
|
||
|
twenty remained. (Guerin, pp. 47-48)
|
||
|
These same observations were made by the members of the
|
||
|
International: "The English section reported on cooperatives.
|
||
|
Without denying the usefulness of cooperative organizations, it
|
||
|
indicated a dangerous tendency noticeable in a majority of such
|
||
|
bodies in England, which were beginning to develop into purely
|
||
|
commercial and capitalist institutions, thus creating the
|
||
|
opportunity for the birth of a new class--the working bourgeoisie."
|
||
|
(Maximoff, p. 47)
|
||
|
The small, isolated, under-capitalized worker cooperatives
|
||
|
could barely survive in competition with their better established
|
||
|
capitalist rivals. The few cooperatives that prospered, often
|
||
|
betrayed their working class supporters and began to operate as
|
||
|
though their facilities were their own private property, aided and
|
||
|
abetted by the laws and existing capitalist businesses. The
|
||
|
failings of the cooperatives had raised the thorny issue of how to
|
||
|
turn the socialization of the means of production from an ideal
|
||
|
into a practical reality. The solution suggested by the
|
||
|
collectivists was to expropriate the means of production from the
|
||
|
capitalists and for the workers' associations to own these
|
||
|
"collectively", no longer recognizing any individual ownership
|
||
|
rights to divide up and sell them. The third Congress of the
|
||
|
International accordingly passed a resolution that the main purpose
|
||
|
of the cooperatives must go beyond narrow self-interest. Instead
|
||
|
their purpose must be support the struggle "to wrench from the
|
||
|
hands of the capitalists the means of production and return them to
|
||
|
their rightful owners, the workers themselves." (Guillaume, p. 70)
|
||
|
As we have seen, in The Principle of Federation (1863),
|
||
|
Proudhon began to sketch the outlines of a sort of economic
|
||
|
federalism before he died. This did not, however, prevent his
|
||
|
mutualist followers from trying to defend his earlier ideas. At the
|
||
|
1869 Basel Congress of the International, a dispute arose over a
|
||
|
resolution calling for the collectivization of the land. The
|
||
|
Proudhonists held out for the right of small farmers to own land
|
||
|
privately, as long as they did not rent out the land for others to
|
||
|
work. Tolain, speaking for the mutualists, suggested the resolution
|
||
|
be changed to read, "The Congress declares that, to realize the
|
||
|
emancipation of the worker, it must transform the leases of
|
||
|
farmland...to contracts of sale: so that ownership, continually in
|
||
|
circulation, ceases to be abusive in itself; and consequently [by
|
||
|
ensuring the individual worker the right to the product of his
|
||
|
labors]...safeguards the liberty of the individual groups."
|
||
|
(Guillaume, p. 197)
|
||
|
Bakunin, speaking for the collectivists, disputed the notion
|
||
|
that private property, even in a limited form, was justified as a
|
||
|
means for safeguarding individual rights.
|
||
|
...the individual is a product of society, and without
|
||
|
society man is nothing. All productive labor is above all
|
||
|
social labor; "production is only possible through the
|
||
|
combination of the labor of past generations with the
|
||
|
present generation, there is not ever labor that can be
|
||
|
called individual labor." He [Bakunin] is thus a
|
||
|
supporter of collective property, not only of the soil,
|
||
|
but of all social wealth. As for the organization of
|
||
|
agricultural production, it is concluded by the
|
||
|
solidarization of the communes, as proposed by the
|
||
|
majority of the commission, all the more willingly that
|
||
|
this solidarization implies the organization of society
|
||
|
from the bottom upwards, while the proposition of the
|
||
|
minority presupposes a State [to guarantee and enforce
|
||
|
the terms of sale]. (Guillaume, p. 197)
|
||
|
To be fair to Proudhon and the mutualists, their waffling on
|
||
|
the issue of private property was not so much due to ambivalence
|
||
|
about collective ownership, as an example of the extremes they were
|
||
|
prepared to go to avoid a revolutionary confrontation. Mutualist
|
||
|
credit was intended to produce "a new economic arrangement" which
|
||
|
would somehow avoid the "shock" of violent confrontation with the
|
||
|
capitalists over their property rights. To the collectivists, who
|
||
|
were veterans of bitter labor strikes and insurrections, this was
|
||
|
hopelessly idealistic. Capitalism had not originated out of a
|
||
|
peaceful, democratic debate as to how to organize production to
|
||
|
ensure economic justice and well-being for all, but was the product
|
||
|
of centuries of fraud, theft, and State-sponsored violence.
|
||
|
Proudhon often ignored that these activities were as much a part of
|
||
|
the functioning of the existing economy as was the official market
|
||
|
side of capitalism. The State and the capitalists would not
|
||
|
disappear with a new set of rules, since they, more often than not,
|
||
|
did not play by their own rules.
|
||
|
Although Proudhon had discovered many of the contradictions
|
||
|
of capitalist economics, his non-confrontational solutions were
|
||
|
just too out of touch with reality. What the anarchists needed was
|
||
|
to base their economics less on moral arguments than on a
|
||
|
positivist materialism. As Bakunin put it:
|
||
|
...Proudhon remained an incorrigible idealist all his
|
||
|
life, swayed at one moment by the Bible and at the next
|
||
|
by Roman Law ...His great misfortune was that he never
|
||
|
studied natural science and adopted its methods....As a
|
||
|
thinker Marx is on the right path. He has set up the
|
||
|
principle that all religious, political and legal
|
||
|
developments in history are not the cause but the effect
|
||
|
of economic developments. Many others before him had a
|
||
|
hand in the unveiling of it and even expressed it in
|
||
|
part, but in the last resort credit is due to him for
|
||
|
having developed the idea scientifically and having made
|
||
|
it the basis of his whole scientific teaching. On the
|
||
|
other hand, Proudhon understood the idea of freedom
|
||
|
better than Marx. (Jackson, pp. 128-129)
|
||
|
|
||
|
Collectivism and Marxism
|
||
|
The criticism Bakunin made of Proudhon's idealism was perhaps
|
||
|
a kinder version of the same criticism Marx had made in The Poverty
|
||
|
of Philosophy. It is on the basis of such statements, as well as
|
||
|
his praise for Marx's Capital, that some argue that Bakunin shared
|
||
|
the economic views of Marx. In reality Bakunin and his fellow
|
||
|
collectivists differed with Marx on economic grounds as well as on
|
||
|
political matters. Bakunin did begin a translation of Capital into
|
||
|
Russian, but never completed it. Had his enthusiasm for the work
|
||
|
been as overwhelming as some claim, he would no doubt have finished
|
||
|
it and collected the remainder of the sum agreed upon by the
|
||
|
Russian publishing house (instead of getting expelled at the Hague
|
||
|
Congress of the International for allegedly threatening the
|
||
|
publisher in order to get out of the deal). A closer look at what
|
||
|
Bakunin thought about Capital reveals his real reason for admiring
|
||
|
the work:
|
||
|
...nothing, that I know of, contains an analysis so
|
||
|
profound, so luminous, so scientific, so decisive and if
|
||
|
I can express it thus, so merciless an expose of the
|
||
|
formation of bourgeois capital and the systematic and
|
||
|
cruel exploitation that capital continues exercising over
|
||
|
the work of the proletariat. The only defect of this
|
||
|
work...is that it has been written, in part, in a style
|
||
|
excessively metaphysical and abstract...which makes it
|
||
|
difficult to explain and nearly unapproachable for the
|
||
|
majority of workers. (Bakunin, p. 195)
|
||
|
Bakunin, more the revolutionary than the economist, admired
|
||
|
Capital as a great piece of revolutionary propaganda. Marx, drawing
|
||
|
his facts and figures out of British government documents and
|
||
|
parliamentary debates, had hoisted the capitalists by their own
|
||
|
petards. This does not mean he endorsed it verbatim. Bakunin had
|
||
|
earlier translated The Communist Manifesto into Russian and made no
|
||
|
bones about his disagreements with Marx and Engels over their
|
||
|
proposals for a centralized state socialist economy.
|
||
|
I am not a communist because communism concentrates and
|
||
|
absorbs all the powers of society into the state, because
|
||
|
it necessarily ends in the centralization of property in
|
||
|
the hands of the state...I want society and collective
|
||
|
property to be organized from the bottom upwards by means
|
||
|
of free association and not from the top downwards by
|
||
|
means of some form of authority...it is in this sense
|
||
|
that I am a collectivist. (quoted in Cahm, p. 36)
|
||
|
Rather than a State or a market determining the allocation of
|
||
|
resources and the distribution of products, the workers would
|
||
|
decide these things themselves by free agreements among the
|
||
|
associations. These agreements would be monitored by the communes,
|
||
|
and industrial federations to make sure that labor was not
|
||
|
exploited. Bakunin, however, recognized that any system of free
|
||
|
exchange of products still held the danger of monopoly and private
|
||
|
accumulation of wealth, particularly by the self-employed farmer or
|
||
|
artisan, who tried to pass on land or equipment to his children.
|
||
|
Thus he also called for the abolition of inheritance to prevent the
|
||
|
rise of a new working class bourgeoisie.
|
||
|
The International debated the subject of inheritance at its
|
||
|
Basel Congress in 1869. Marx was opposed to the International
|
||
|
taking a position on the subject of inheritance on the grounds that
|
||
|
once the private ownership of the means of production had been
|
||
|
abolished (and expropriated by the workers' government), there
|
||
|
would be nothing left to inherit. Even worse, it implied the
|
||
|
International would support something other than the state
|
||
|
communism of Marx. As Eccarius, speaking for Marx, put it, "the
|
||
|
abolition of the right of inheritance can not be the point of
|
||
|
departure for the same social transformation: it would be too
|
||
|
absurd to require the abolition of the law of supply and demand
|
||
|
while continuing the state of conditions of exchange; it would be
|
||
|
a reactionary theory in practice. By treating the laws of
|
||
|
inheritance, we suppose necessarily that individual ownership of
|
||
|
the means of production would continue to exist." (Guillaume, p.
|
||
|
201)
|
||
|
Eccarius was half right. Bakunin and the other collectivists
|
||
|
intended that something other than the state ownership of the means
|
||
|
of production and central control would exist, but it would not
|
||
|
necessarily be capitalist ownership nor a market economy. The full
|
||
|
collectivization of the economy would not be carried out by a
|
||
|
single decree, but over a generation. Abolition of wage labor by
|
||
|
the collectivization of the capitalist employers would be the first
|
||
|
step, but the right of the self-employed, particularly the small
|
||
|
farmer, to their means of livelihood would be respected. To
|
||
|
recognize this right of possession to the tools needed for one's
|
||
|
own labor, however, was not to recognize an ownership right that
|
||
|
could be bought and sold or passed on to one's children. This was
|
||
|
the meaning behind the collectivist demand for the abolition of
|
||
|
inheritance.
|
||
|
If after having proclaimed the social liquidation, we
|
||
|
attempted to dispossess by decree millions of small
|
||
|
farmers, they would necessarily be thrown onto the side
|
||
|
of reaction, and in order for them to submit to the
|
||
|
revolution, it would be necessary to employ force against
|
||
|
them...It would be well then to leave them possessors in
|
||
|
fact of those small parcels of which they are
|
||
|
proprietors. But if you don't abolish the right of
|
||
|
inheritance what would happen? They would transfer their
|
||
|
holdings to their children...If, to the contrary, at the
|
||
|
same time that you would make the social liquidation...
|
||
|
you abolish the right of inheritance what would remain
|
||
|
with the peasants? Nothing but defacto possession, and
|
||
|
that possession... no longer sheltered by the protective
|
||
|
power of the state, would easily be transformed under the
|
||
|
pressure of events and of revolutionary forces. (Bakunin,
|
||
|
quoted by Guillaume, p. 203)
|
||
|
|
||
|
The Collectivist Economic Doctrine
|
||
|
Collectivism, unlike Proudhon's Mutualism or Marxism, was not
|
||
|
a well developed theory, the product of a single mind. Its
|
||
|
principal advocates were socialist revolutionaries and workers
|
||
|
caught up in the events of the time: the upheavals of 1848 which
|
||
|
occurred throughout Europe, the birth of the labor unions, and the
|
||
|
Paris Commune of 1871. As far as they could tell, a social
|
||
|
revolution was not an abstract goal looming far off in the
|
||
|
distance, but something that had to be prepared for right away.
|
||
|
Some sort of workable economic program had to be agreed upon by the
|
||
|
labor movement, which had broad appeal to the various socialist and
|
||
|
labor groupings that made up the International, without locking
|
||
|
everyone into something they might regret later. This explains why
|
||
|
collectivism often was so sketchy in details, and some of its
|
||
|
advocates disagreed among themselves over various points.
|
||
|
The closest thing to a "definitive" statement of collectivism
|
||
|
is an essay written by James Guillaume in 1874, "Ideas on Social
|
||
|
Organization" (see Dolgoff, pp. 356-379). Guillaume begins by
|
||
|
emphasizing that there can be no "blueprint" for social revolution,
|
||
|
since it must be left up to the workers themselves to decide how
|
||
|
best to organize themselves in their own areas. However, having
|
||
|
said that, he begins to make various suggestions about the
|
||
|
collectivist approach. First the system of wage labor will be
|
||
|
abolished by the workers "taking possession" of all capital and
|
||
|
tools of production, ie. the collectivization of property. The
|
||
|
self-employed and the owners of family businesses are to be left
|
||
|
alone to operate as they wish, but with this important exception:
|
||
|
"his former hired hands, if he had any, will become his partners
|
||
|
and share with him the products which their common labor extracts
|
||
|
from the land." (Dolgoff, p. 359)
|
||
|
The internal organization of the worker collectives, working
|
||
|
conditions, hours, distribution of responsibilities, and share of
|
||
|
income, etc., are to be left in the hands of their members: "Each
|
||
|
workshop, each factory, will organize itself into an association of
|
||
|
workers who will be free to administer production and organize
|
||
|
their work as they think best, provided that the rights of each
|
||
|
worker are safeguarded and the principles of equality and justice
|
||
|
are observed." (Dolgoff, p. 363, my emphasis)
|
||
|
However the fact that the collectivists were willing to
|
||
|
tolerate those groups which decided to distribute income according
|
||
|
to hours worked, does not mean the collectivists believed in the
|
||
|
principle, "to each according to their work." As Guillaume makes
|
||
|
clear, this is only justified (where it is practiced) as a
|
||
|
temporary expedient, to discourage over-consumption during the
|
||
|
transition period when capitalist conditions of scarcity will not
|
||
|
yet have been overcome.
|
||
|
In some communities remuneration will be in proportion to
|
||
|
hours worked; in others payment will be measured by both
|
||
|
the hours of work and the kind of work performed; still
|
||
|
other systems will be experimented with to see how they
|
||
|
work out. The problem of property having been resolved,
|
||
|
and there being no capitalists placing a tax on the labor
|
||
|
of the masses, the question of types of distribution and
|
||
|
remuneration become secondary. We should to the greatest
|
||
|
possible extent institute and be guided by the principle
|
||
|
From each according to his ability, to each according to
|
||
|
his need. When, thanks to the progress of scientific
|
||
|
industry and agriculture, production comes to outstrip
|
||
|
consumption, and this will be attained some years after
|
||
|
the Revolution, it will no longer be necessary to
|
||
|
stingily dole out each worker's share of goods...
|
||
|
(Dolgoff, p. 361)
|
||
|
Although collectivism promotes the greatest autonomy for the
|
||
|
worker associations, it should not be confused with a market
|
||
|
economy. The goods produced by the collectivized factories and
|
||
|
workshops are exchanged not according to highest price that can be
|
||
|
wrung from consumers, but according to their actual production
|
||
|
costs. The determination of these honest prices is to be by a "Bank
|
||
|
of Exchange" in each community (obviously an idea borrowed from
|
||
|
Proudhon).
|
||
|
...the [labor] value of the commodities having been
|
||
|
established in advance by a contractual agreement
|
||
|
between the regional cooperative federations [ie.
|
||
|
industrial unions] and the various communes, who will
|
||
|
also furnish statistics to the Banks of Exchange. The
|
||
|
Bank of Exchange will remit to the producers negotiable
|
||
|
vouchers representing the value of their products; these
|
||
|
vouchers will be accepted throughout the territory
|
||
|
included in the federation of communes. (Dolgoff, p. 366)
|
||
|
The Bank of Exchange ...[will] arrange to procure goods
|
||
|
which the commune is obliged to get from outside sources,
|
||
|
such as certain foodstuffs, fuels, manufactured products,
|
||
|
etc. These outside products will be featured side by side
|
||
|
with local goods...and all goods will be uniformly
|
||
|
priced. [Since similar goods all have the same average
|
||
|
labor value.] (Dolgoff, p. 367)
|
||
|
Although this scheme bears a strong resemblance to Proudhonian
|
||
|
"People's Banking," it should be noted that the Banks of Exchange,
|
||
|
along with a "Communal Statistical Commission," are intended to
|
||
|
have a planning function as well.
|
||
|
...each Bank of Exchange makes sure in advance that these
|
||
|
products are in demand [in order to risk] nothing by
|
||
|
immediately issuing payment vouchers to the producers.
|
||
|
(p. 367) ....By means of statistics gathered from all the
|
||
|
communes in a region, it will be possible to
|
||
|
scientifically balance production and consumption. In
|
||
|
line with these statistics, it will also be possible to
|
||
|
add more help in industries where production is
|
||
|
insufficient and reduce the number of men where there is
|
||
|
a surplus of production. (Dolgoff, p. 370)
|
||
|
As conditions permit, the exchange functions of the communal
|
||
|
banks are to be gradually replaced by the distribution of goods "in
|
||
|
accordance with the needs of the consumers." (p. 368) Until that
|
||
|
point is reached, the local community has the responsibility for
|
||
|
providing certain basic needs for everyone without regard for
|
||
|
production done by that particular individual. Among these
|
||
|
essential needs to be distributed freely are education, housing,
|
||
|
health, personal security and fire protection, disaster relief, and
|
||
|
food services. The worker collectives engaged in these essential
|
||
|
communal services will not be required to exchange them for their
|
||
|
"labor value," but "will receive from the commune vouchers enabling
|
||
|
them to acquire all commodities necessary for the decent
|
||
|
maintenance of their members." (Dolgoff, p. 365)
|
||
|
Therefore each "commune" is to provide a basic standard of
|
||
|
living for all its members during the transitional period leading
|
||
|
towards economic abundance. Those people desiring a higher income
|
||
|
will be given the right of access to the means of production in
|
||
|
order to produce goods both for themselves and for exchange. Each
|
||
|
worker collective, however, will not have to shift for itself but
|
||
|
will receive assistance from the communes, and local and regional
|
||
|
industry associations.
|
||
|
...social organization is completed, on the one hand by
|
||
|
the establishment of regional corporative federations
|
||
|
comprising all the groups of workers in the same
|
||
|
industry; and on the other by the establishment of a
|
||
|
federation of communes....The corporative federations
|
||
|
will unite all the workers in the same industry; they
|
||
|
will no longer unite to protect their wages and working
|
||
|
conditions against the onslaughts of their employers, but
|
||
|
primarily to guarantee mutual use of the tools of
|
||
|
production which are the property of each of these groups
|
||
|
and which will by a reciprocal contract become the
|
||
|
collective property of the whole corporative federation.
|
||
|
In this way, the federation of groups will be able to
|
||
|
exercise constant control over production, and regulate
|
||
|
the rate of production to meet the fluctuating consumer
|
||
|
needs of society....The statistics of production,
|
||
|
coordinated by the statistical bureaus of every
|
||
|
corporative federation, will permit the determination in
|
||
|
a rational manner of the hours of labor, the cost price
|
||
|
of products and their exchange value, and the quantities
|
||
|
in which these products should be produced to meet the
|
||
|
needs of consumers. (Dolgoff, pp. 376-377)
|
||
|
|
||
|
A Limited Form of Communism
|
||
|
In his essay, "Must We Apply Ourselves with an Examination of
|
||
|
the Ideal of a Future System?", Peter Kropotkin pointed out that
|
||
|
the anarcho-collectivism advocated by Bakunin, Guillaume, and the
|
||
|
anarchists in the First International, was actually a variety of
|
||
|
anarchist communism, but "in an altered and limited form" (Miller,
|
||
|
p. 59). The anarcho-collectivists felt that full communism, ie. the
|
||
|
free distribution of all goods and services, would have to wait
|
||
|
until the economy had been reorganized and the scarcity
|
||
|
artificially created by the capitalist market had been overcome.
|
||
|
Until then much of production would be according to the principle
|
||
|
of "to each workplace according to their product." This is not the
|
||
|
same as the state collectivists who argued for "to each worker
|
||
|
according to their work," and called for elaborate schemes of
|
||
|
income hierarchy. The worst that can be said about the anarcho-
|
||
|
collectivists, is that they were willing to tolerate income
|
||
|
differences at various workplaces for the sake of giving each
|
||
|
collective the autonomy to decide for themselves. This was,
|
||
|
however, not their ideal. Even for the transition period, the
|
||
|
anarcho-collectivist principle was income equality for all working
|
||
|
in the same collective.
|
||
|
Do not the manager's superior training and greater
|
||
|
responsibilities entitle him to more pay and privileges
|
||
|
than manual workers? Is not administrative work just as
|
||
|
necessary to production as is manual labor--if not more
|
||
|
so? Of course, production would be badly crippled, if not
|
||
|
altogether suspended, without efficient and intelligent
|
||
|
management. But from the standpoint of elementary justice
|
||
|
and even efficiency, the management of production need
|
||
|
not be exclusively monopolized by one or several
|
||
|
individuals. And the managers are not at all entitled to
|
||
|
more pay... (Bakunin, quoted in Dolgoff, p. 424)
|
||
|
A much more serious problem for collectivism is the inequality
|
||
|
which would inevitably arise between workers due to the exchange of
|
||
|
products. The collectivists sought to ameliorate this to a certain
|
||
|
extent by giving the investment arm of the communes, the Banks of
|
||
|
Exchange, a more activist role in economic planning, and by putting
|
||
|
an income floor under all workers by providing free housing, food,
|
||
|
and public services. However, this creates further possible sources
|
||
|
of inequality, since the communal service workers are supposed to
|
||
|
work in return for meeting all their needs regardless of their
|
||
|
productivity. Thus a possible source of conflict arises between a
|
||
|
communist service sector and an exchange-based production sector.
|
||
|
If the production goes well, the communal workers may resent the
|
||
|
higher incomes gained by the production workers. If production goes
|
||
|
poorly, the production workers may resent the income security of
|
||
|
the service workers.
|
||
|
For the collectivists these problems were seen as minor, if
|
||
|
recognized at all. Guillaume, for instance, assumed that the
|
||
|
material abundance developed during the transitional period would
|
||
|
bring about a blossoming of morality, which would soon make the
|
||
|
exchange economy irrelevant. Unfortunately, this begs the question,
|
||
|
since he did not bother to define what "abundance" is and how we
|
||
|
are to know when we have achieved it. We can safely predict that in
|
||
|
any future economy there is virtually no limit to human desires for
|
||
|
material goods, while there will always be limits to what society
|
||
|
and the ecology are able to provide without causing a breakdown.
|
||
|
"Abundance" means different things to different people.
|
||
|
The danger is that by leaving this point of development undefined,
|
||
|
those who may be the economic"winners" of the transitional period,
|
||
|
may be unwilling to make the next step.
|
||
|
|
||
|
The Collectivist Legacy
|
||
|
The main contribution of the collectivists to anarchist
|
||
|
economics was their attempt to anticipate many of the problems
|
||
|
which would be encountered during the revolutionary transition from
|
||
|
capitalism to stateless communism, and their emphasis on the need
|
||
|
for finding a balance between ultimate goals and day-to-day
|
||
|
realities. These methods contributed enormously to the early
|
||
|
successes of the 1936 revolution in Spain, where the anarchist
|
||
|
movement retained a strong collectivist tradition. The specific
|
||
|
proposals made by Guillaume and others, while useful as an example
|
||
|
of applying anarchist principles to existing conditions, have lost
|
||
|
most of their relevance. We do not live in 19th century europe nor
|
||
|
1930s Spain, but in a high-tech economy threatened by environmental
|
||
|
exhaustion. In most industries, technology has developed well
|
||
|
beyond the point needed for "abundance" in 19th century terms. This
|
||
|
makes the question of defining the minimum level of abundance all
|
||
|
the more important for modern anarchists, as well as the more
|
||
|
practical problem of how to go beyond a crude exchange economy
|
||
|
during the transition.
|
||
|
|
||
|
BIBLIOGRAPHY
|
||
|
|
||
|
Bakunin, M. Obras Completas, Volume III. Translated by
|
||
|
Santillan, Buenos Aires, 1926.
|
||
|
Cahm, Caroline. Kropotkin and the Rise of Revolutionary
|
||
|
Anarchism 1872 - 1886. Cambridge University Press, 1989.
|
||
|
Dolgoff, Sam. Bakunin on Anarchism. Black Rose Books,
|
||
|
Montreal, 1980.
|
||
|
Guerin, Daniel. Anarchism. Monthly Review Press, 1970.
|
||
|
Guillaume, James. L'Internationale : Documents et Souvenirs
|
||
|
(1864 - 1878). Paris, 1905. 4 volumes.
|
||
|
Jackson,J. Marx, Proudhon and European Socialism. Collier, New
|
||
|
York, 1966.
|
||
|
Maximoff, G.P. Constructive Anarchism. Chicago, 1952.
|
||
|
Miller, Martin A. Selected Writings on Anarchism and
|
||
|
Revolution: P.A. Kropotkin. M.I.T. Press, 1970.
|
||
|
|
||
|
(I would like to thank Nan DiBello for her assistance with this
|
||
|
article.)
|